Economics and Financial Issue

↑ Grab this Headline Animator

| 4 comments ]

Accumulation of international reserves beyond the optimal level has its risks and costs

THE world has caught a bad cold. According to the October 2008 IMF World Economic Outlook Report, the world economy, battered by the most dangerous financial shock since the 1930s and by still-high energy and commodity prices, is entering a major downturn and many advanced economies are already close to or moving into recession.

The biggest worry for almost every Malaysian right now is the resilience of Malaysia’s economy. Can it ride out smoothly the global economic crisis even though half the world is already in recession?

Comments have been made that Malaysia’s economy will not slide into a recession because, among others, its international reserves are high. As at end-September 2008, Malaysia’s international reserves stood at US$107.6bil.

What are international reserves? Is it a case of “more is better?”

Also popularly known as foreign exchange reserves, international reserves are assets that a central bank holds in different reserve currencies, such as the dollar, euro and yen, and to a very much smaller extent, gold and International Monetary Fund (IMF) Special Drawing Rights. These assets are basically used to finance international transactions, to serve as a buffer stock to face unexpected payments difficulties, and to allow implementation of monetary and foreign exchange rate policies.

International reserves accumulation has been the favoured policy of most developing economies since the Asian financial crisis (1997-98). During the crisis, the scale and speed of the reversal of capital flows had resulted in sharp contractions in output and investments, credit crunches, and banking crises in several countries.

The rapid accumulation of reserves after the crisis suggests that it is a precautionary adjustment, a reflection of the desire to self insure against exposure to future sudden stops, rather than to depend on institutions like the IMF. For example, a country with a large stockpile of reserves will be able to lay to rest fears of potential defaults on foreign debt payments by the government or the private sector and, therefore, avoids being shut out of the international capital markets. In many cases, however, this precautionary motive seems to have been replaced by a strategic motive of using the reserves to manage exchange rates at a certain desired level or range.

The enormous accumulation of reserves in Asia has been so rapid that the Asian Development Bank has warned they are now well beyond the optimal levels. Reserves accumulation may over time entail risks and costs like inflationary pressure, over-investment, asset bubbles and complications in the management of monetary policy.

There is also the risk that the balance sheets of monetary authorities may face potentially sizeable capital losses. For example, not all risks may have been taken into account when the unprecedented increase in world reserves were partly used to fund the seemingly forever-growing US deficits. China is a case in point. With more than US$1.5 trillion in reserves denominated in US dollars, it has become a hostage to its debtor, i.e. the United States. China is stuck, and any hint of it moving to shift away from the US dollar in the currency composition of its reserves would be devastating. One can only guess the extent of the carnage in the financial markets and the world economy if that were to happen.

Persistent reserves accumulation suggests a strong external sector with significant trade and current account surpluses, which is certainly true for Malaysia. It has been consistently registering trade and current account surpluses for over a decade.

While a persistent trade surplus can be interpreted as a sign of export competitiveness due to rising productivity or falling costs, it is more than likely that an undervalued ringgit is the reason in Malaysia’s case, and which obviously cannot go on forever.

A persistent current account surplus in the face of large reserves, on the other hand, can be interpreted as a sign of an inherently weak domestic economy, driven mainly by exports.

According to the absorption approach to interpreting balance of payments statistics, the current account balance is the difference between national income and domestic absorption, where absorption is defined as the sum of private consumption expenditure, investment and government expenditure. A current account surplus, thus, suggests there is weak domestic demand, and that there is a glut of domestic savings.

As such, more international reserves do not necessarily mean better, and a large stockpile should not be mistaken as a sign of economic resilience. Besides, reserves accumulation entails risks and costs. Malaysia’s stockpile of reserves should thus not lull us into a false sense of economic security, especially during the current global economic turmoil with half the world already in recession and external demand expected to shrink further.

According to Bank Negara, the optimal level of reserves for Malaysia is between US$30bil and US$40bil. As Malaysia’s level of reserves is way above the optimal level, an alternative use could be found for the excess reserves to build a more dynamic domestic sector and, therefore, render the economy more resilient in the face of external shocks. In Taiwan, for example, US$15bil was allocated to banks for use in major investment projects.

The writer is a research fellow at the Malaysian Institute of Economic Research.

4 comments

Ivo Cerckel said... @ December 22, 2008 at 1:52 PM

The optimal level of reserves for Malaysia is one gold dinar per paper dinar in circulation.
http://bphouse.com/blaze/honest_money/

Ivo Cerckel said... @ December 22, 2008 at 5:05 PM

The only way to get rid of the dollar hegemon is to replace our forex reserves with gold dinar reserves.

The next step is to mark these reserves to market (-price), not to the model of 42 dollars an ounce like the USA treasury department (don’t ask me why not the USA central bank),

Every increase in the value of gold dinar will then lead to an increase in the value of the ringgit.

The maladministration by dollar international financial and monetary system (dollar-IFMS) is systemic and thus finite.
Hence, the gold dinar will return as money because it is a vote of non-confidence vis-a-vis the dollar-IFMS.

A new IFMS, without the dollar, will only be able to inspire trust/confidence if it will allow the gold dinar to exist alongside itself.

Next problem: What happens when Bank Negara acquires more gold dinars? Will it then have to issue more paper dinars, more ringgits?

The aim is to achieve stability through equilibrium. How will Bank Negara achieve that when it acquires more gold dinars? I am still trying to figure that out. Help welcome. ivocerckel@siquijor.ws

Ivo Cerckel said... @ December 23, 2008 at 10:45 AM

TO
Next problem: What happens when Bank Negara acquires more gold dinars? Will it then have to issue more paper dinars, more ringgits?
The aim is to achieve stability through equilibrium. How will Bank Negara achieve that when it acquires more gold dinars? I am still trying to figure that out.

I receive this REPLY by Ender on another site:
http://www.goldforum.com/forum/showthread.php?p=484#post484
At first glance, it would seem that your thinking fixes gold dinars to paper dinars, yet I believe you will find that the paper dinars should be linked to the functioning of the economy.
I, too, would like to understand this better. I hope time permits.

Ivo Cerckel said... @ December 23, 2008 at 12:48 PM

Ender says;
At first glance, it would seem that your thinking fixes gold dinars to paper dinars, yet I believe you will find that the paper dinars should be linked to the functioning of the economy

Reisman says;
The quantity theory of money holds that the volume of spending in the economic system, for goods, for labour, or any other broad category of things, is determined primarily by the quantity of money that exists in the economic system
(George Reisman, “Capitalism – A Treatise on Economics”, Ottawa, Illinois Jameson Books, 1998, 3rd ed., p. 504)

The theory shows that the cause of generally rising prices is an increase in the quantity of money. More specifically, it shows that the cause is an increase in the quantity of money at a rate more rapid than the increase in the supply of gold and silver.
(Reisman, p. 895)

Ivo says;
No link here to the functioning of the economy. The only link is to the increase in the supply of gold and silver.

Or is there such a link?
Monetary headaches for dollar-peg nations
Last Updated: December 22. 2008 8:22PM UAE / December 22. 2008 4:22PM GMT
http://thenational.ae/article/20081222/BUSINESS/630648764/1005
SNIP
Following the Dec 16 Fed rate cut, the Saudi monetary authority immediately slashed its repo rate 50 basis points. By contrast, the UAE Central Bank governor appeared to fold, refusing to drop his rate any lower at the current time. This apparent emergence of a more independent streak in policy setting is perhaps good news for the individual economies of the GCC, yet it is bad news for the prospects of early currency union.

Post a Comment

Kehidupan Hari-Hariku....